Top

Effective Tax Rates on U.S. Multinationals’ Foreign Income under Proposed Changes by House Ways and Means and the OECD

Summary: The House Ways and Means Committee reforms proposed as part of budget reconciliation would more than triple the U.S. tax rate on multinationals’ foreign income and produce a higher rate than a proposed global agreement currently being negotiated through the OECD.

Key Points

  • The Tax Cuts and Jobs Act of 2017 (TCJA) taxation of multinationals’ foreign income maintained a similar overall tax burden: both before and after TCJA, multinationals paid an effective U.S. tax rate of around 2 percent on their foreign income.

  • The House Ways and Means Committee reforms proposed as part of budget reconciliation would more than triple the U.S. tax rate on multinationals’ foreign income, from around 2.1 percent to 7.4 percent, averaged by foreign income across industries. If the U.S. instead adopted the draft OECD proposal, U.S. multinationals would pay a residual U.S. tax rate of 6.1 percent.

  • The future competitiveness of U.S. multinational firms depends critically on whether other OECD countries also increased their tax rates.


Effective Tax Rates on U.S. Multinationals’ Foreign Income under Proposed Changes by House Ways and Means and the OECD

Introduction

Effective tax rates (ETRs) reflect the amount of tax paid on a dollar of income, accounting for tax credits, differences between actual income and taxable income, and other factors that cause the true tax burden to differ from the statutory tax rate.1

Prior to passage of TCJA in 2017, all foreign income was notionally subject to tax at the statutory rate of 35% as it was earned. But foreign income was generally not recognized for U.S. tax purposes unless paid out as a dividend to U.S. taxpayers (repatriated), and multinationals could defer U.S. taxes on most foreign income indefinitely by retaining it in foreign affiliates. Under this system, multinationals could minimize or eliminate their U.S. tax liability through judicious timing of repatriations. In aggregate, PWBM estimates that multinationals paid ETRs (excluding Subpart F income) between 1.4% and 2.8%, or less than one tenth of the statutory rate of 35%.

The option to defer taxation indefinitely, combined with the expectation of eventual tax “holidays” on foreign income, led to the accumulation of substantial amounts of un-repatriated income abroad. Though nominally controlled by foreign affiliates, this income was typically deposited in U.S. banks or invested in U.S. assets. Major multinationals could generally access this income through the financial system and use it as though it had been repatriated, including to pay dividends or finance domestic investment. Less financially sophisticated firms, however, faced a choice between paying the statutory rate of 35%, holding a stock of accumulated earnings abroad, or reinvesting such earnings in their foreign operations. In all cases, the tax planning incentives created by deferral resulted in additional complexity and cost.

The pre-TCJA international tax regime is commonly referred to as a worldwide system because foreign income was notionally subject to tax as it was earned. In practice, recognition of most foreign income was deferred with no tax paid, resulting in what was effectively a territorial system for most major multinationals.

After TCJA

The regime introduced by TCJA is generally commonly to as a territorial system because most foreign income is exempt from tax upon repatriation. However, some foreign income is taxed as it is earned, with no option of deferral. While this income is taxed at a preferential rate, mandatory current inclusion of foreign affiliates’ income in U.S. parents’ taxable income results in what is effectively a worldwide system for many multinationals. According to a former House senior tax counsel who played a leading role in the development of TCJA, “Most U.S. [multinationals] believe we moved the system closer to pure worldwide even if we messaged it as moving closer to territorial.”

TCJA introduced a minimum tax on multinationals’ foreign income through the Global Intangible Low-Taxed Income (GILTI) regime. Taxes on GILTI are determined on an aggregate basis, based on a taxpayer’s consolidated global operations. Income from profitable foreign affiliates can be offset by losses from other affiliates, and tax credits from high-tax affiliates can be used to offset liability arising from low-tax affiliates.

This aggregate determination of tax liability is consistent with a multinational operating in multiple countries for business reasons – for example, a manufacturing facility in a low-cost country and a sales office in a market country. However, aggregate determination also allows a multinational to benefit from shifting income to tax havens, as foreign taxes paid in high-tax jurisdictions can be used as a credit against U.S. residual tax on tax haven income.

Proposed Changes by U.S. House and OECD

The U.S. is currently the only OECD country that imposes a minimum tax on the foreign income of its multinationals. A recent proposal from the House Ways and Means Committee would magnify this difference, increasing the tax burden on U.S. corporations’ foreign income to finance increased spending and cuts in other taxes as part of a budget reconciliation package. However, ongoing negotiations through the OECD/G20 Inclusive Framework on BEPS would – if successful – lead to the adoption of a global minimum tax by more than 130 countries, including the home countries of nearly every major foreign multinational.

Both the recent Congressional proposal and the proposed global minimum tax under negotiation through OECD would shift the determination of taxes on foreign income from an aggregate basis to a country-by-country basis. Instead of treating a multinational as single global entity with components in various jurisdictions, its activities in each country would be treated as independent operations. Minimum tax would be imposed separately for each country rather than on a consolidated basis. Under country-by-country determination, tax haven income is taxed at the minimum rate regardless of taxes paid elsewhere.

Table 1 presents estimated ETRs in 2022 and other information under alternative international tax regimes: current law, the pre-TCJA regime, and three proposed reforms that would raise revenue. Row 1 shows the rate of residual tax imposed by the U.S. on foreign income, on top of taxes already paid to foreign governments. Row 2 shows the total ETR, including both U.S. and foreign taxes. Row 3 shows the projected 10-year change in revenue for the three proposed alternatives. Rows 4 to 15 detail the parameters of each international tax regime. These projections are preliminary as they are based on current information available for House and OECD proposals; we will update these estimates as new details.

Table 1: Estimated 2022 ETRs Under Alternative International Tax Regimes

DOWNLOAD DATA
Current law Pre-TCJA equivalent* House proposal House proposal without country-by-country OECD Pillar 2
1 Residual US ETR on MNEs' foreign income 2.1% 1.4 - 2.8% 7.4% 5.1% 6.1%
2 Combined US and foreign ETR on MNEs' foreign income 12.7% 12 - 13.4% 18% 15.7% 16.7%
3 Revenue, 2022-2031, changes to GILTI and FDII (billions) - - 256 107 144
4 Corporate tax rate 21% 35% 26.5% 26.5% 26.5%
5 GILTI deduction 50% Deferral 37.5% 37.5% 43.4%
6 FTC haircut 20% 0% 5% 20% 0%
7 GILTI effective statutory tax rate 10.5 - 13.125% 35% 16.6 - 17.4% 16.6 - 20.7% 15%
8 Deduction for return on tangible assets 10% 0% 5% 5% 7.5%
9 Deduction for return on labor 0% 0% 0% 0% 7.5%
10 Country-by-Country No No Yes No Yes
11 NOL carryforwards No No Yes No Yes
12 FTC carryforwards No Yes Yes No Yes
13 Include FOGEI in GILTI No Yes Yes Yes Yes
14 FDII deduction 37.5% 0% 21.875% 21.875% 37.5%
15 FDII effective statutory tax rate 13.125% 35% 20.7% 20.7% 16.6%

Source: PWBM
Notes: Foreign income includes all income of foreign affiliates except Subpart F income.
ETR = effective tax rate; MNE = multinational enterprise.
* Pre-TCJA policy is mapped to approximate post-TCJA-equivalent concepts. ETRs reflect U.S. residual tax paid in a given year on all foreign income (except Subpart F income) and are given as a range to reflect annual variability in the timing of repatriations.

The proposed reforms would lead to substantially higher minimum ETRs than the current GILTI regime. The House proposal would impose a country-by-country minimum tax of between 16.6 and 17.4 percent. PWBM estimates that if this proposal were adopted, the residual U.S. tax rate on multinationals’ foreign income would rise from 2 percent under current law to 7.4 percent.

The draft OECD proposal would impose a country-by-country minimum tax of 15 percent. PWBM estimates that if the U.S. were to conform its minimum tax to the OECD proposal, the residual U.S. tax rate on multinationals’ foreign income would rise from 2 percent under current law to 6.1 percent.

Figures 1, 2, and 3 report estimated country-level ETRs in 2022 for major foreign jurisdictions where U.S. multinationals report income, for current law and the alternative tax regimes. Because U.S. taxes are assessed at the group level and a multinational group may operate in multiple countries, U.S. tax liability is not directly attributable to specific countries. The plotted ETRs reflect an estimate of the additional tax resulting from scaling up global operations such that net income is $1 higher, holding all else constant.

Figure 1 shows ETRs for the recent House Ways and Means proposal. Figure 2 reports an alternative which retains all elements of the Ways and Means proposal except the shift to country-by-country. Country-by-country determination effectively eliminates any benefit of reporting income in a low-tax country. Under aggregate determination, such benefits are reduced but not eliminated.

Figure 1: Effective tax rates on foreign income, Current law vs. House proposal

DOWNLOAD DATA

Note: Foreign income includes all income of foreign affiliates except Subpart F income.

Figure 2: Effective tax rates on foreign income, Current law vs. House proposal without country-by-country

DOWNLOAD DATA

Note: Foreign income includes all income of foreign affiliates except Subpart F income.

Figure 3: Effective tax rates on foreign income, Current law vs. OECD Pillar 2

DOWNLOAD DATA

Note: Foreign income includes all income of foreign affiliates except Subpart F income.

Competitiveness

The U.S. House Ways and Means proposal as part of budget reconciliation would more than triple the U.S. tax rate on multinationals’ foreign income, from around 2.1 percent to 7.4 percent, averaged by foreign income across industries. The House proposal would tax U.S. multinationals at a higher rate than the proposed global agreement currently being negotiated through the OECD. If the U.S. instead adopted the draft OECD proposal, U.S. multinationals would pay a residual U.S. tax rate of 6.1%.

The future competitiveness of U.S. firms depends on whether other countries adopt the OECD proposal.

  • Case 1 -- U.S. status quo / OECD status quo: If neither the U.S. nor OECD countries changed their tax regimes, U.S. companies would continue to face a small disadvantage, as under current law.

  • Case 2 -- U.S. status quo / OECD adopts OECD proposal: If the U.S. retained its current minimum tax regime while other countries adopted the OECD proposal, U.S. multinationals would gain an advantage in terms of competitiveness and relative profitability, compared with a small disadvantage under current law.

  • Case 3 -- U.S. adopts House / OECD adopts OECD proposal: If the U.S. adopted reforms recently proposed by the House Ways and Means Committee while OECD countries adopted the OECD proposal, U.S. multinationals would face a generally level playing field, albeit a small disadvantage similar to current law discussed in Case 1.

  • Case 4 -- U.S. adopts House / OECD status quo: If the U.S. substantially adopts the House proposal, but OECD countries maintain status quo, U.S. multinationals would face a meaningful competitive disadvantage. Notably, foreign multinationals could continue to exploit tax havens to increase their profitability, while U.S. multinationals would not be able to take full advantage of such tax planning opportunities.

Students of economics will quickly recognize these potential “payoffs” as being consistent with the classic Prisoner’s Dilemma game from the field of game theory. In that setting, Case 1 is the “dominant strategy equilibrium” if the game is played only once. However, Case 4 can emerge if the game is (i) repeated many times and (ii) international sanctions are created to punish countries that “cheat” by lowering their tax rate. However, Case 4 also requires substantial cooperation across many countries, including from traditional tax havens like Ireland that have not yet agreed to the OECD proposal.



This analysis was conducted by Alexander Arnon and Zheli He. Prepared for the website by Mariko Paulson.


  1. We calculate the ETR on foreign income as the ratio of income taxes paid or accrued to foreign financial (book) income. Taxes paid or accrued include both foreign and U.S. taxes, except taxes on Subpart F income. Foreign income includes all income earned by U.S. multinationals outside of the U.S., except Subpart F income. We exclude Subpart F income because it is treated separately from other foreign income and is generally taxed as though it were domestic income.  ↩

  Country	Income	Foreign Tax Rate	Current law	House proposal
  Ghana	1355.51643	0.115325685	0.11532568	0.15952905
  Mauritius	1237.56934	0.043631777	0.08556444	0.16285396
  Morocco	190.83765	0.18903286	0.18903286	0.18903286
  Zambia	63.39351	0.194823714	0.19482371	0.19482371
  Americas, other countries	7395.16145	0.078571036	0.0964527	0.14014102
  Barbados	12324.80676	0.002970986	0.04293114	0.13870565
  Bermuda	98565.34496	0.004736657	0.05465741	0.16273773
  Canada	41769.94638	0.174866555	0.17486656	0.17486656
  Cayman Islands	54175.10102	0.003534074	0.05046987	0.15824116
  Chile	4778.32239	0.14400062	0.14400062	0.16554434
  Costa Rica	3425.88037	0.044960692	0.07358952	0.15753748
  Dominican Republic	821.12811	0.082448455	0.09504668	0.15588432
  Honduras	591.11677	0.062910988	0.08095641	0.15776821
  Panama	854.30937	0.096888637	0.0991185	0.14921294
  Paraguay	65.84264	0.18548275	0.18548275	0.18548275
  Puerto Rico	37772.64162	0.014707921	0.0660176	0.16001947
  Uruguay	429.15189	0.11135807	0.11936275	0.13576371
  Venezuela	154.26724	0.072221995	0.07885071	0.072222
  Virgin Islands	91.69348	0.040924153	0.05488719	0.04092415
  Hong Kong	16575.59765	0.10060311	0.10933452	0.16302571
  Israel	4495.09826	0.181981657	0.18198166	0.18198166
  Korea, Republic of (South)	6350.49203	0.069271136	0.08316088	0.14413581
  Lebanon	78.03946	0.090618678	0.10948854	0.15802542
  Macau	3422.71504	0.002646866	0.01163956	0.12328866
  Malaysia	4984.79394	0.182903271	0.18290327	0.18290327
  Saudi Arabia	886.67825	0.143385092	0.14338509	0.15794799
  Singapore	83516.10849	0.038878254	0.07844948	0.16167993
  Sri Lanka	82.70645	0.112415991	0.11806252	0.16389572
  Taiwan	3866.93197	0.185892368	0.18589237	0.18589237
  United Arab Emirates	2771.042	0.023439127	0.02343913	0.13444375
  Vietnam	882.76132	0.125048538	0.12530709	0.1614352
  Bosnia-Herzegovina	16.8933	0.067686969	0.08492034	0.12604761
  Bulgaria	236.63203	0.085856974	0.08585697	0.13028817
  Croatia	163.77816	0.141755319	0.14175532	0.16776315
  Cyprus	885.11437	0.027792182	0.07557491	0.11357672
  Czech Republic	1503.33125	0.169035161	0.16903516	0.17276054
  Europe, other countries	58271.78789	0.002712607	0.06417058	0.16072517
  Finland	1058.67332	0.172666757	0.17266676	0.17349708
  Hungary	2092.03151	0.164715982	0.16471598	0.17245691
  Ireland	59233.74438	0.126989394	0.12698939	0.16619275
  Latvia	20.76769	0.097200984	0.10330712	0.14432122
  Lithuania	260.11509	0.147995042	0.14799504	0.1689853
  Luxembourg	61562.14742	0.016137711	0.05241533	0.12058346
  Netherlands	71284.42167	0.055969925	0.07337806	0.13964113
  Norway	2970.51569	0.123836908	0.12383691	0.13840958
  Poland	3268.15107	0.178390336	0.17839034	0.17839034
  Romania	726.27897	0.155020318	0.15502032	0.16562806
  Serbia	145.06398	0.155832761	0.15583276	0.16725614
  Slovenia	73.25819	0.160669432	0.16066943	0.16882458
  Switzerland	63062.55897	0.065565083	0.08548436	0.15575803
  United Kingdom	92380.82052	0.112680824	0.1132009	0.13523282
  Country	Income	Foreign Tax Rate	Current law	House proposal ex. country-by-country
  Ghana	1355.51643	0.115325685	0.11532568	0.14802728
  Mauritius	1237.56934	0.043631777	0.08556444	0.12124486
  Morocco	190.83765	0.18903286	0.18903286	0.19547769
  Zambia	63.39351	0.194823714	0.19482371	0.2004525
  Americas, other countries	7395.16145	0.078571036	0.0964527	0.13848127
  Barbados	12324.80676	0.002970986	0.04293114	0.08083532
  Bermuda	98565.34496	0.004736657	0.05465741	0.1010227
  Canada	41769.94638	0.174866555	0.17486656	0.18479512
  Cayman Islands	54175.10102	0.003534074	0.05046987	0.09902639
  Chile	4778.32239	0.14400062	0.14400062	0.16238459
  Costa Rica	3425.88037	0.044960692	0.07358952	0.11522604
  Dominican Republic	821.12811	0.082448455	0.09504668	0.13126777
  Honduras	591.11677	0.062910988	0.08095641	0.12129074
  Panama	854.30937	0.096888637	0.0991185	0.12492331
  Paraguay	65.84264	0.18548275	0.18548275	0.18901074
  Puerto Rico	37772.64162	0.014707921	0.0660176	0.10200605
  Uruguay	429.15189	0.11135807	0.11936275	0.1531487
  Venezuela	154.26724	0.072221995	0.07885071	0.13142153
  Virgin Islands	91.69348	0.040924153	0.05488719	0.09606805
  Hong Kong	16575.59765	0.10060311	0.10933452	0.14540572
  Israel	4495.09826	0.181981657	0.18198166	0.18977868
  Korea, Republic of (South)	6350.49203	0.069271136	0.08316088	0.11834367
  Lebanon	78.03946	0.090618678	0.10948854	0.14499134
  Macau	3422.71504	0.002646866	0.01163956	0.05499369
  Malaysia	4984.79394	0.182903271	0.18290327	0.19044808
  Saudi Arabia	886.67825	0.143385092	0.14338509	0.16423854
  Singapore	83516.10849	0.038878254	0.07844948	0.11480181
  Sri Lanka	82.70645	0.112415991	0.11806252	0.15312464
  Taiwan	3866.93197	0.185892368	0.18589237	0.19020659
  United Arab Emirates	2771.042	0.023439127	0.02343913	0.09226985
  Vietnam	882.76132	0.125048538	0.12530709	0.15284252
  Bosnia-Herzegovina	16.8933	0.067686969	0.08492034	0.11875091
  Bulgaria	236.63203	0.085856974	0.08585697	0.10181747
  Croatia	163.77816	0.141755319	0.14175532	0.16595053
  Cyprus	885.11437	0.027792182	0.07557491	0.1122699
  Czech Republic	1503.33125	0.169035161	0.16903516	0.18025793
  Europe, other countries	58271.78789	0.002712607	0.06417058	0.1006466
  Finland	1058.67332	0.172666757	0.17266676	0.18022512
  Hungary	2092.03151	0.164715982	0.16471598	0.18066518
  Ireland	59233.74438	0.126989394	0.12698939	0.15951819
  Latvia	20.76769	0.097200984	0.10330712	0.13210296
  Lithuania	260.11509	0.147995042	0.14799504	0.17090362
  Luxembourg	61562.14742	0.016137711	0.05241533	0.10382299
  Netherlands	71284.42167	0.055969925	0.07337806	0.12286053
  Norway	2970.51569	0.123836908	0.12383691	0.1519035
  Poland	3268.15107	0.178390336	0.17839034	0.18528795
  Romania	726.27897	0.155020318	0.15502032	0.16806311
  Serbia	145.06398	0.155832761	0.15583276	0.17009388
  Slovenia	73.25819	0.160669432	0.16066943	0.17165095
  Switzerland	63062.55897	0.065565083	0.08548436	0.12765698
  United Kingdom	92380.82052	0.112680824	0.1132009	0.13790547
  Country	Income	Foreign Tax Rate	Current law	OECD Pillar 2
  Ghana	1355.51643	0.115325685	0.11532568	0.13598073
  Mauritius	1237.56934	0.043631777	0.08556444	0.14501386
  Morocco	190.83765	0.18903286	0.18903286	0.18903286
  Zambia	63.39351	0.194823714	0.19482371	0.19482371
  Americas, other countries	7395.16145	0.078571036	0.0964527	0.10975335
  Barbados	12324.80676	0.002970986	0.04293114	0.1176146
  Bermuda	98565.34496	0.004736657	0.05465741	0.15003759
  Canada	41769.94638	0.174866555	0.17486656	0.17486656
  Cayman Islands	54175.10102	0.003534074	0.05046987	0.14482432
  Chile	4778.32239	0.14400062	0.14400062	0.14553155
  Costa Rica	3425.88037	0.044960692	0.07358952	0.13583716
  Dominican Republic	821.12811	0.082448455	0.09504668	0.1335238
  Honduras	591.11677	0.062910988	0.08095641	0.13870412
  Panama	854.30937	0.096888637	0.0991185	0.13360405
  Paraguay	65.84264	0.18548275	0.18548275	0.18548275
  Puerto Rico	37772.64162	0.014707921	0.0660176	0.14250606
  Uruguay	429.15189	0.11135807	0.11936275	0.11135807
  Venezuela	154.26724	0.072221995	0.07885071	0.072222
  Virgin Islands	91.69348	0.040924153	0.05488719	0.04092415
  Hong Kong	16575.59765	0.10060311	0.10933452	0.14441102
  Israel	4495.09826	0.181981657	0.18198166	0.18198166
  Korea, Republic of (South)	6350.49203	0.069271136	0.08316088	0.11722558
  Lebanon	78.03946	0.090618678	0.10948854	0.12752409
  Macau	3422.71504	0.002646866	0.01163956	0.0903694
  Malaysia	4984.79394	0.182903271	0.18290327	0.18290327
  Saudi Arabia	886.67825	0.143385092	0.14338509	0.14338509
  Singapore	83516.10849	0.038878254	0.07844948	0.14257399
  Sri Lanka	82.70645	0.112415991	0.11806252	0.1341934
  Taiwan	3866.93197	0.185892368	0.18589237	0.18589237
  United Arab Emirates	2771.042	0.023439127	0.02343913	0.10469953
  Vietnam	882.76132	0.125048538	0.12530709	0.13607751
  Bosnia-Herzegovina	16.8933	0.067686969	0.08492034	0.09120403
  Bulgaria	236.63203	0.085856974	0.08585697	0.0952493
  Croatia	163.77816	0.141755319	0.14175532	0.14536429
  Cyprus	885.11437	0.027792182	0.07557491	0.09380441
  Czech Republic	1503.33125	0.169035161	0.16903516	0.16903516
  Europe, other countries	58271.78789	0.002712607	0.06417058	0.14529259
  Finland	1058.67332	0.172666757	0.17266676	0.17266676
  Hungary	2092.03151	0.164715982	0.16471598	0.16471598
  Ireland	59233.74438	0.126989394	0.12698939	0.14664428
  Latvia	20.76769	0.097200984	0.10330712	0.10892119
  Lithuania	260.11509	0.147995042	0.14799504	0.14799504
  Luxembourg	61562.14742	0.016137711	0.05241533	0.10945952
  Netherlands	71284.42167	0.055969925	0.07337806	0.12304335
  Norway	2970.51569	0.123836908	0.12383691	0.12383691
  Poland	3268.15107	0.178390336	0.17839034	0.17839034
  Romania	726.27897	0.155020318	0.15502032	0.15502032
  Serbia	145.06398	0.155832761	0.15583276	0.15583276
  Slovenia	73.25819	0.160669432	0.16066943	0.16066943
  Switzerland	63062.55897	0.065565083	0.08548436	0.13503922
  United Kingdom	92380.82052	0.112680824	0.1132009	0.11268082